The post that follows was written as a Twitter thread. As a result no paragraph is more than 280 characters long. But it grew, and grew, and the issue it addresses - the role of quantitative easing (QE) in the economy over the last decade is vital. Breaking it down into a lot of paragraphs does no harm as a result. So, this is my explanation of how QE works and what results. Much of it is new. It also predicts work that is to come. I hope it it useful.
–––-
There's massive misunderstanding about what QE is and what it does. So please forgive a long thread on one of the most important tools used in modern economics, which if used properly might provide real hope for a better future.
Outside Japan QE was unknown until 2009. Since then the UK has done £845 billion of it. This is a big deal as a consequence. But as about half of that has happened this year it's appropriate to suggest that there have been two stage of QE, so far. And I suggest we need a third.
Stage 1 QE started in 2009 and was last used in 2016. It created £445bn of new money. That was used to buy £435bn of government bonds, or gilts, and £10bn of corporate bonds, which we can ignore. There were three goals to first stage QE.
The first was to keep interest rates down. The Bank of England calls QE monetary policy for a reason. Buying gilts in the financial markets pushes up their price. And since the return paid on them is fixed if their price goes up the effective interest rate paid on them goes down.
The second reasons was to provide liquidity to banks and financial institutions. This liquidity froze in 2008. It was solved because QE created money ends up being held by banks and building societies on the central bank reserve accounts they hold at the Bank of England.
Since 2008 banks and building societies have not trusted each other to not go bust, overnight. After all, Lehman Brothers did. So they don't give each other credit any more. Instead they have to hold central bank reserve account balances to settle their debts to each other.
QE boosted the balances on central bank reserve accounts. In 2009 these amounted to £42bn. In February 2020, when the last audited figure was published, they were £479bn. They have probably gone up by another £400 billion or more by now as a result of QE this year.
So, QE provided the money to make sure that the banking system could still function. It should not fall over again in the way it almost did in 2008 as a result, although it had a good go at doing so in March this year, which is why the Bank of England intervened so heavily then.
Third, it has to be remembered that QE began in 2009. Back then it was still the official line that banks needed deposits before they could lend. That was not true. It hasn't been since at least 1971. But this was not acknowledged by the Bank of England until 2014.
Given that this ‘old world' view on deposits and lending prevailed the BoE thought QE would enable banks to lend more to boost the economy. That was nonsense, and the evidence proved it. Creative lending to promote employment remained as rare as ever within UK banking despite QE.
What QE did instead was two things. First, it released money to buy other assets. Speculation in commodities such as oil and metals increased significantly, and even pushed up inflation. But falling interest rates also did something else. It pushed up share prices.
Just as high gilt prices push down gilt interest rates, so too do low interest rates make shares look more attractive and so push up their prices. A steady increase in share prices followed. By 2019 they had roughly doubled since 2009, although they have fallen since.
It should be added that there is one big problem with all this money going into shares. Little, if any of it actually ends up in the companies that issue the shares in question. It's just speculative activity in existing shares. It was great for the City, but almost no one else.
The ‘almost' in that last sentence was deliberate. QE also benefited the government. Despite the claim that it faced a debt crisis that required austerity the QE programme from 2009 to 2012, totalling £375bn, meant that most government debt in that period was funded by QE.
Let's be clear what ‘funded by QE' means. The funding is not direct. All government spending is initially paid for by the Bank of England making payment on government command. The overdraft this might create is then by convention cleared by a mix of tax receipts and debt issues.
The debt the government issues to clear a deficit on its account with the Bank of England (which is what the term really means) can last for a few days to more than 50 years. And all of that debt can be traded, or sold, on the City money markets.
People want to own that debt. Banks, building societies, pension funds, life assurance companies, foreign governments, individuals even, all appreciate owning this debt because it's the safest form of saving available in the UK in sterling. UK debt's great stuff that people want.
When QE is used to buy this debt back, because that's what it does, the Bank of England does so using a company called the Bank of England Asset Purchase Facility Fund Limited, or APF for short. This is owned by the Bank of England but, there is a twist.
The APF might be owned by the Bank, but it is effectively controlled by the UK Treasury, which consents in writing to all that it does, including all QE spending. And the Treasury also underwrites all its losses (it has not had many of them) and is entitled to all its profits.
What is more, although the interest on the gilts the APF owns is still paid, the interest actually goes straight back to the Treasury as income, effectively cancelling it, of course. So there are political shenanigans going on here.
The first shenanigan is that the so-called independence of the Bank of England from the Treasury is blown apart by the fact that the Treasury completely controls the APF and the whole QE process. QE is a Treasury operation in practice, not a Bank of England one.
The second shenanigan is that the claim that QE does not cancel debt is blown apart by the fact that repurchased debt is not really owned by the Bank of England but is owned by the Treasury, which gets all the income and profits from it.
Importantly, you can't, of course, owe yourself money. A debt requires that you owe a third party. But the Treasury does not do that, because the government also owns the Bank of England. But how the mechanics of this works needs explanation.
To undertake QE the BoE lends the APF money. Like all bank loans, this one is created out of thin air. The BoE promises to pay whoever the APF instructs it to make payment to. The APF promises to repay the loan. The two promises create the new money that the debt represents.
The APF then uses its new funds to buy gilts. It uses an auction process, paying the market price as a result. The people selling usually profit, often considerably, as a result. After the repurchase the APF legally owns the repurchased gilts, but the Treasury does in reality.
None of the gilts bought by the APF have ever been sold back to financial markets. Such is the scale of likely deficits in the future it is wholly unrealistic to think that they ever will be. So, once the APF buys these gilts it is now reasonable to think that they are cancelled.
The Bank and government do not agree. They say they could be resold. They do this to pretend the debt still exists. They are included in national debt calculations although no one is owed any money. And the interest on them is still treated as a cost to the gov't, which it isn't.
There is only one possible explanation for this pretence, which is that this maintains the austerity narrative. The pretence that there is a debt to repay, and an interest cost to settle, is used as an excuse to cut government spending even though no such excuse exists.
It is appropriate to note what really happens to the money paid by the APF to buy gilts. Even now, when QE is heading to be more than £800 billion, it simply becomes money deposited by the UK's banks and building societies on central bank reserve accounts with the Bank of England.
So the question is whether or not this is a debt? In a normal bank it would be. Customer deposits in normal banks are liabilities. They are money owing to customers that the bank could have to pay out on and find the money to settle. But the Bank of England is not a normal bank.
The deposits UK banks have with the Bank of England only exist because the Bank of England created that money in the first place. And only they, amongst banks, can create money by lending within their own organisation i.e. within government. So this is different from other money.
That difference has real impact. First, the UK's banks can't in effect get rid of these deposits. All they can do is transfer them between them. Only government can cancel these deposits, by charging extra tax or selling new bonds and letting the deposits be used to make payment.
In that case these deposits aren't debt. They are, instead, money created by the BoE. And just in case there is doubt as to whether money created by the Bank of a England is debt or not, bank notes are not in the ONS national debt figures. So nor should this new money be, either.
Interest is paid on these central bank reserve accounts. It's settled at BoE base rate. That's 0.1% right now. But that's convention. This need not be the case. The Bank of a England could change the rules if interest rates rose and there would be nothing banks could do about it.
So, not only under conventional QE is the debt repurchased effectively cancelled, as is the interest on it, but it's replaced by newly created money that is not part of the national debt.
Think about it: government created money can't be part of the national debt because it can only be repaid using more new government created money. That means repayment would create new money exactly equivalent to the amount repaid, so it cannot be debt in any conventional sense.
The result is stage 1 QE benefitted the banks, enormously; lifted asset prices, like shares, considerably; let the government cancel most of its new debt from 2009 to 2012; and left the austerity story completely intact so that most people were economically conned by this.
What has happened in stage 2 of QE, which is the 2020 story? The mechanism is identical is the first thing to say. None of that needs retelling, at all. The figures have just gone up by more than £400 billion all round, that's all.
But the motivation was different. The first stage of this happened in March. As coronavirus lock down happened that month the banks froze. They were back to 2008 and seemingly unwilling to function. £200 billion of new QE then was intended to simply free up the markets.
That worked. Andrew Bailey claimed he was a super hero as a result. Actually, he just did his job as creator of new money, which is what the markets needed to unblock the jam that was created as banks thought they faced Armageddon.
But the £200 billion also did something else. As it became obvious government deficits would sky rocket new QE provided all the funds required for markets to acquire the new debt the government was issuing, and at the same time still keep interest rates low.
Literally, what the QE process did was pump money into the financial markets as a result of the repurchase of gilts, which money was then available to buy the new gilts the government had to offer because of significant deficit spending.
The difference between stage 1 and stage 2 QE then becomes clear. In stage 1 there could be a pretence that the QE funds were part of monetary policy to control interest rates. They just happened, coincidentally to effectively cancel government debt as well.
In stage 2 QE, for anyone with the willingness to look at what was really happening it was apparent that the Bank of England was actually deliberately creating the funds required to fund government spending in advance of them being needed. It was as simple as that.
With £450 billion of QE planned for 2020/21 and an anticipated deficit of around £400 billion when allowance is made for the profit many gilt owners make in reselling their bonds to the government is taken into account the Bank of England is almost wholly funding the deficit.
So, when the question is asked ‘who is lending money to the government right now?' The answer is ‘No one'. Instead every penny of the deficit is being paid for with newly created money that is being provided by the Bank of England. And national debt is not in rising as a result.
Of course, the newly created money goes somewhere. It ends up in the central bank reserve accounts held with the Bank of England by the UK's banks and building societies. These are likely worth more than £800 billion now. All earning interest at 0.1%.
There is a good question to ask about why these banks earn 0.1% on money they did not seek. But that's for another day. More important is the fact that in net terms in Stage 2 QE there is no money to reinvest elsewhere in the economy.
That's because the markets effectively sold no gilts back to the government. Unlike Stage 1 QE, in Stage 2 QE the overall impact is that the Bank of England is simply funding new gilt issues. It's directly funding the government. The markets are almost removed from the equation.
This is not, in that case, monetary policy, even if it does keep interest rates low. This is fiscal policy, in effect. This is about deficit financing. The pretence that the BoE does QE for monetary policy reasons is shattered. It is not. Nor is it in any way independent.
We have reached the point where in reality the claim that the government cannot borrow from its central bank is shown to be a myth. It is doing just that, with the Bank using newly created money that ends up on central bank reserve accounts, to do so.
But this also means that there is no argument for austerity. There is no new debt. And no one is owed anything to repay the central bank reserve account balances, because they are just money. And until there is full employment this new money creation creates no risk of inflation.
So, any claim that we are suffering under a mountain of debt is just wrong. If anything, because of the scale of gilt repurchased national debt is at most stable in amount. It might actually be going down.
Stage 2 QE is not, however, what is prescribed by modern monetary theory. None of the artificial structures that QE uses are in any way required by MMT. It says that the Bank of England should actually just run an overdraft for the government, which is what is really happening.
But whether Stage 2 QE is what modern monetary theory would prescribe is not the point. MMT does explain what is happening. A government in the situation we face in 2020 can fund itself using new money creation. That is exactly what is happening.
Crucially, there is no debt as a result. There is only new money. The amount of that money is wholly under government control. And there is no inflation risk at this moment. Not need there be, external shocks like Brexit apart. This is a completely stable situation.
So, tales that borrowing has reached its limits and that austerity is required, or that we are saddling future generations with debt are all nonsense. No one can, or needs to, repay the new money the government has created.But the government has to understand that.
If the government does not understand this it can do something catastrophic. It can increase overall tax, which would crush demand in the economy, and so increase unemployment. Or it can cut spending, which has the same result.
The government can suck the lifeblood out of the economy, in other words. By choosing to believe its own austerity narrative it can deliver an economic disaster. George Osborne had a good go at this. Rishi Sunak might try to do so again.
What should the government do? Stage 3 QE is my answer. This is quite different to stages 1 and 2. In stages 1 and 2 there's no direct link between government spending and QE. It's indirect. Spend creates the deficit, requiring bonds to clear it, which requires QE to cancel them.
In Stage 3 QE the link to spending is explicit. In this stage the government plans economic recovery. Call it a Green New Deal. A Green or National Investment Bank funds this programme. It issues bonds to pay for the investment. The Bank of England uses QE to but those bonds.
Now QE is explicitly created in advance to fund spending. It does not mop up after the event. It is used to provide the money need to transform our economy. This does not mean other savers cannot provide funds as well. I have argued that this option should be available.
But, the intention is to show that a lack of private sector and private saver willingness to fund the economic transformation we need to recover and sustain our economy should not prevent that transformation taking place. Government has the power to make this change happen.
That power comes from its ability to create money for social benefit. This has been used so far to save our banks, and to fund COVID created deficits. Now it could be used to fund the transition to a sustainable economy we need if no other sources are available.
The government should try to secure capital required from other sources, by all means. But doing so is not a constraint. For a government in the position of the UK government, a lack of money is not a constraint. How much money there is in the economy is its to decide.
Of course it has to consider inflation. That can be controlled if it is economically rather politically created (the latter being of the sort Brexit will deliver) by additional taxes, bond sales, or cuts in spending. But we have no risk of that type of inflation right now.
So Stage 3 QE could deliver the recovery we so desperately need, if linked to investment, in particular.
What is necessary is that the power of QE be understood. Few have tried to do that. There are few politicians in that number. But it's time QE - or the the power to create money - was understood. Because this is how we control and deliver the economy of the future.
Thanks for reading this post.
You can share this post on social media of your choice by clicking these icons:
You can subscribe to this blog's daily email here.
And if you would like to support this blog you can, here:
Thank you.
My understanding is that customer deposits made with High Street banks, legally become the property of the bank, and therefore do not show as liabilities. The banks undertake to return all or part of any deposit on demand, only if it suits them to do so. That is stated in the bank’s terms and Conditions to depositors. So if a High Street bank went bust its Receiver or Administrator would not have to repay any depositors money. In reality the government would likely tell the Receiver to return all depositors money, and also the depositors are protected by the governments £85,000 scheme if their bank goes bust. But anything over £85,000 could be lost?
Yes, in a word
But that does not mean that they are not recorded as liabilities: they are. But they are unsecured liabilities i.e. you take the risk on repayment.
A totally schizophrenic position. The majority of UK voters believe the the government shouldn’t be in debt but want to own some of it!
“… almost all of human history can be written as the search for and the production of different forms of safe assets.”
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2770569
Contrast with:-
“Let us never forget this fundamental truth: the State has no source of money other than money which people earn themselves. If the State wishes to spend more it can do so only by borrowing your savings or by taxing you more. It is no good thinking that someone else will pay–that “someone else” is you. There is no such thing as public money; there is only taxpayers’ money.”
http://www.margaretthatcher.org/document/105454
Or
“An exchange on public-sector pay followed, with Corbyn asking for specifics on a pay rise for NHS staff, which May did not provide. Instead there was a mini-lecture on public finances — “the government has no money of its own” — which allowed Corbyn the obvious retort that finding £1bn for the DUP’s support had not proved problematic.”
https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2017/oct/18/pmqs-verdict-corbyns-easy-win-on-the-economy-should-worry-tories
It would be good to find a convenient way to turn that pernicious Thatcher quote on its head.
First attempt: “Let us never forget this fundamental truth: the State is the only source of money in the economy. If you wish to earn, invest or spend some money, you can only do that by getting some money from the State (or from the banks which the State allows to create money by lending) and which the State has not yet recouped in tax. It is no good thinking there is any other source of money – it all comes from the State. There is no such thing as taxpayer’s money; there is only public money.”
(If someone thinks there is any “taxpayer’s money”, which has been created by a private body, not by the state or one of its licensees, I suggest they try printing and spending some of their own and see how far that gets them.)
Andrew wrote: “It would be good to find a convenient way to turn that pernicious Thatcher quote on its head.”
Richard Murphy has, in effect, already done this. In an online course on MMT which I’m teaching through the Henry George School of Social Science in New York City, my lecture notes for tonight include this from his 2015 book The Joy of Tax:
“When you first encounter MMT, you are probably startled by the notion that, as Murphy puts it, ‘… no government has to charge tax to be able to spend on what it wants to do.’ (52) Murphy goes farther, rejecting the rhetorical trope of ‘the taxpayers’ money’. The money you pay in taxes is the government’s money and the government’s rightful property. (44) ‘[P]aying tax is actually the process by which we transfer to the government that part of the funds we hold which rightfully are not ours but are in fact the property of the state. … Tax is actually the government’s money that we sometimes hold on its behalf.’ (46)”
Thanks
Still hearing the same line ‘taxes will have to rise/spending will have to be cut to repay the borrowing’ on TV (local and national), on radio (local and national), on t’interntet.
Craig
Depressing, isn’t it?
Very. And frustrating.
Craig
Thanks Richard. For me, the 280-character Twitter constraint has resulted in your most informative MMT article yet.
Perhaps those in Government (with a short attention span equal to or less than mine) will dip in to your bite-sized words of wisdom.
It would be churlish to hope that all Brexiteers choke on your comment about politically created inflation but I’m allowed to wish them severe indigestion.
🙂
A bravura exposition Richard, covering all the issues. thank you. A couple of minor things, in para 15 you use the accounting term “cleared”. For a layperson like me, this is a bit opaque. Maybe “balanced” would be better? And para 23 ( I think) you say ” a debt requires that you owe a third party”. Don’t you just need two parties to a debt?
Cleared is a good point
A third party is simply someone other than yourself
Richard,
Like one of your twitter followers, I was triggered by Marr’s “£200bn debt needs repaid!” observation this morning. I keep asking/telling people, “Who is this money owed to? “ and “Have the banks repaid this debt after 2009?” Thank you for articulating this point. Something struck me about the Marr claim as well. Scotland’s share of this “debt” was almost equivalent to the annual assigned debt Scotland “owes” yet Marr stated that this level of spending was unprecedented save in times of war….an interesting aside that implies Scotland spends as if she were in a permanent state of war!
Marr was clueless……
“The government should try to secure capital required from other sources” – would that then be “real debt” ie money owed to third parties? Perhaps “all sources” are not equal if that means capital coming in from other countries, other financiers, possibly in foreign currencies rather than being created as Government money?
I have no problem with savers investing in real assets, if the saving is in Sterling. Better that than money in the stock market
Best Twitter thread I’ve seen for ages. Read it earlier. Well done for persevering.
Am I alone, as a fellow CA, (membership lapsed for 30 years), in wanting all this reduced to simple double entry. None the less a brilliant article. But the search for the Holy Grail of an explanation of MMT such that a serious politician would go to bat with it, continues. A serious step in the right direction though.
Sorry – no time to do that
I am also a CA and interested in Economics but not an Economist. I think the double-entry is possible but you have to be careful what entities you consider and which ones are to be consolidated. After much scribbling, the conclusions are straightforward.
First the answer;
If the Government spends money, then on a Consolidated basis the entries are ;
Dr Expenditure (Fixed Asset or Revenue Expenditure as appropriate)
Cr Bank Accounts due to Private Sector
or
Cr Gilts due to Private Sector
This suggests the Government can spend money and either fund it through the issue of gilts or the creation of money. I think the art in this decision is to consider the implications. Gilts will require interest payments and ultimately re-paying or re-financing. Money creation incurs no interest cost but has implications for inflation, exchange rates and interest rates. Thus, the accounting is straightforward but the economics is not.
In reality, bookkeeping is carried out by individual entities and not the whole Government as a group. When money is created, at B of E ;
Dr LT Loan due by Treasury
Cr Cash – Treasury ie money Tresury can now spend.
At Treasury;
Dr Cash at BofE, ie recognise there is cash to spend
Cr LT Loan due to Treasury
If you were to consolidate at this stage, the quadruple-entry would cancel itself out. All we have doen is create entires so that Treasury can draw on a cash balance.
In the long-term and in economic reality, the loan due by Treasury to BofE is not important and disappears on consolidation.
Treasury then spends the money on Expenditure (but it could be Gilts ie QE)
At Treasury ;
Dr Expenditure
Cr Cash at B of E
At B of E
Dr Cash due to Govt ie Govts cash is reduced
Cr Cash due to Private Sector Banks
[We could account for Banks and Private Sector here but time and space do not permit. A ripple of entries through the economy ends up with money in Private Sector bank accounts]
The end result is the Government can create its own money and spend it, and for the Government as a whole (for accountants, consolidated) the credit will go to Gilts or Money Supply. These will both appear as debts and are legal obligations but I get the impression the money supply is unlikly to be reduced although there are many ins and outs every day.
The book-keeping is consistent with Richard’s analysis but there are real economic variables to take into account. At the end of the day, a country’s production is the total goods and services that can be produced. This is really a function of demographics, education, technology, legal and travel infrastructure and other real-world issues. The Government can extract some of that production to itself via tax, money creation or borrowing but how it does that will have knock-on consequences for interest-rates, inflation and exchange-rates which in turn, will affect economic performance and livelihoods. For me, inflation includes the values of real and financial assets. This is a system that is delicately balanced and I guess (no real knowledge) that Treasury and B of E will spend a lot of time being concerned with funding expenditure with the minimum of knock-on problems.
Thanks
I will muse on that
[…] Cross-posted from Tax Research UK […]
I have a question to help me understand the mechanics.
If the APF buys gilts on the open market my understanding from your article is it’s banks, insurance companies and pension funds the APF is buying from.
My question is why can’t these institutions use their funds in any way they want?
“it simply becomes money deposited by the UK’s banks and building societies on central bank reserve accounts with the Bank of England.”
You seem to suggest the funds have to be held on account by banks. Why is this? And is it just the banks or do insurance companies and pension funds also have the same?
They can – bit the money that is created still exists – if they buy another asset the recipient still banks the proceeds – and that ends up back on the central bank reserve accounts – that’s simply what happens, pretty much as a matter of fact
That money moves – and can also vary in amount depending on taxes paid and ongoing guilt transactions but it retains a pretty much overall consistent relationship with the sums owed too and from government as a result of QE and maybe some other government-based transactions.
[…] because answers to some quite critical questions are only now becoming apparent. The blog that I published yesterday on quantitative easing is, however, one of the outcomes. The effort has been worth it, but sometimes I have been […]
A good narrative. I might have expressed some of the details in the early sections slightly differently but the key point is how QE has morphed from Interest Rate management to funding deficit spending – we have MMT by accident.
Getting this more widely understood would be a great achievement…. so keep it up!!
Your suggested edits would be appreciated – by email if need be
Wasn’t a National Investment Bank part of Labours 2019 election policy?
So is it likely that under the present party leadership it will be retained? Was that not at least the first necessary step? But now not much mentioned?
The Tories are now planning to do it…
Can we stop calling it QE and start calling it what it is?
Overt Monetary Financing
Calling it QE just keeps the obfuscation train on track.
But that would only mean no one would know what I’m talking about
The clearest explanation I’ve seen yet. I wondered Richard, if you’d had any feedback from the wider world of economists and media commentators? Constructive or otherwise. Or whether it would be worth asking for it by circulating it to them and asking for comment.
As is so often observed here, the big challenge is getting the current narrative challenged and a wider public debate going.
I am an insider in that very closed world
Steve Keen likes it….
Well Steve would!
I was wondering about some more middle ground, Keynsians perhaps and Then the economics correspondents in the media, most of whom seem startlingly limited in their thinking.
Working on the latter
As a young chap, my understanding of the lectures on Kreb’s cycle usually lasted till I reached the car park. I’m doing a bit better with MMT.
There’s an outfit that illustrates “talks” on a sort of whitebard animation – I’d find that useful.
I’d love to walk on versions of this….
I like the delineation between QE stage 1 and 2 and that stage 3 is a neat extension.
Only thing I would add is that QE Stage 1 wasn’t the only help the banks got, prior to 2009 QE the banks had been receiving up to £62bn in emergency liquidity funding(via the loan of T bills in exchange for bank assets like mortgages). This was in fact done in entire secrecy throughout 2008/09 . Then came the £125bn public state buyout of bank shares ,added to which there was a £134bn Capital Guarantee Scheme and the increase in deposit insurance from £35k to £50K….later extended to £85K in 2011.
All in all the banks got very well looked after.
Fair cop!
Forgive me if this is beyond the scope of your article.
You mention austerity as a narrative to be maintained. My question is simply, why? Who or what does this narrative serve?
See https://www.taxresearch.org.uk/Blog/2020/11/20/austerity-is-a-sado-masochistic-ritual-for-a-powerful-elite/
Very urgently needed.
Is anyone able to produce a ‘motion to Council’ asking government to fund local authorities so they have the money to pay for social care, fit for pupose public services and respond to the climate and ecological crisis?
Richards explanation of QE would be a really good commentary to such a demand.
I could have a go but it needs to be couched in language that the treasury would understand?
We need to be pushing for this, not wait for the unlikely chance that we have a elected a political class that understands MMT. Time is fast running out.
I am not familiar with motions to0 Council…
[…] claim that QE can only happen because the Bank of England is 'incredibly independent'. Actually, as I explained yesterday, absolutely everything about QE is wholly under the control of the […]
Sorry about the jargon.
Motions to council. eg. Sheffield City Council, are the wording of a policy proposal that is debated by all elected councillors. The outcome, often with amendments, is recorded and acted on by the council executive.
It could be worded something like ‘This Council instructs the chief executive to ask a Government Minister to explain why funds generated through QE is borrowing when the BoE said in 2014 (provide reference) said…etc. ”
Obviously my wording here could be avoided by the Govt Minister but I hope you get the gist. There could be pre- amble about the impact of austerity already unable to deliver a fit for purpose service to the public.
Continuous questions on financial matters every month to the Minister could be made by a Council until there is clarity into what is actually possible.
If the same or similar questions could be tabled by councils across the country (eg the 12 Core Cities in England) pressure could build to ensure the truth will actually be revealed.
Bonds repurchased by QE by the BoE seem to be able to exist and not exist at the same time. Should we call them Schrodingers cache?
🙂
Some of those in the quantum business are a bit sniffy about Schrodinger’s Cat these days.
However, quantum entanglement exists and occurs when two particles become inextricably linked, and whatever happens to one immediately affects the other, regardless of how far apart they are. Hence the ‘spooky action at a distance’ description.
So regardless of Andrew Bailey’s wishes, the distance from the BoE to HMT is not far enough to escape entanglement.
PS: Here’s a photo of quantum entanglement taken at my alma mater, the University of Glasgow –
https://www.sciencealert.com/scientists-just-unveiled-the-first-ever-photo-of-quantum-entanglement
I note that the quantum entanglement ( QE ! ) experiment involved the use of a SPAD. Let’s hope it wasn’t Damian McBride.
Damn! I was so entranced by my own verbiage, I didn’t spot quantum entanglement = QE.
🙂