A comment on this blog, posted this morning, made me realise that when I talk about political economy, which is a phrase that recurs throughout my writing, not everybody understands what I mean. I am not referring to an academic sub-discipline or an abstract branch of theory. I am talking about the only way that economics can, in my opinion, make sense.
Economics is not, and never has been, a neutral science. It is a social practice. It describes how human beings organise the resources available to them, whether they be labour, other species, capital, or the planet we live on, and, in doing so, express their choices about power, ownership, and fairness. Those choices are inherently political. To pretend otherwise is to disguise ideology as mathematics, which is what economics, as it is now taught, does.
That, in essence, is what political economy means to me. It is the study of how power and policy shape economic outcomes, and how economic outcomes, in turn, shape power and policy.
That said, it might be appropriate to add a bit more explanation to this.
First, political economy begins by acknowledging that there is no such thing as an economy separate from society. Every economic act, from a wage negotiation to a tax policy, happens within a political context. When governments decide how to spend, who to tax, or which industries to subsidise, they are not responding to immutable laws of supply and demand. They are making moral and political choices about what sort of society we wish to live in.
Second, political economy insists that the state is not a bystander. It is the most powerful actor in the economic system, as the issuer of our currency, the provider of public goods, a regulator of markets, and guarantor of rights. To deny that role, as neoliberal economists have done for decades, is to retreat into fantasy. Markets do not exist in a vacuum: they are built, sustained, and shaped by law, policy, and the institutions of government.
Third, political economy looks at who benefits. It asks the questions that mainstream economics avoids. These are issues like:
- Who gains from this structure of ownership?
- Who bears the cost of this form of taxation, which might be very different from who appears to pay it?
- Whose labour is undervalued, and
- Whose wealth is protected the most?
It is in these questions that the real moral content of economics becomes visible.
Fourth, political economy is historical. It understands that today's arrangements, such as the privatised utilities, the deregulated finance sector, and the dominance of shareholder value, are not inevitable. They were created by policy choices that reflected particular ideologies and interests. And they can, equally, be changed.
The consequences of ignoring political economy, as I understand it, are all around us.
When governments claim that “there is no money left,” they hide from public view the reality of sovereign currency creation and the capacity of the state to fund what it chooses to value.
When policy is reduced to the “sound finance” of balanced budgets and fiscal rules, we end up with a politics that manages deliberately created scarcity instead of building sufficiency.
When economics is stripped of politics, it becomes a convenient alibi for inequality. It allows wealth to accumulate unchallenged and poverty to be dismissed as individual failure. It turns questions about justice, security, and dignity based on real-life experience into technical debates about productivity and growth.
In other words, the depoliticisation of economics is itself a political act, and one designed to preserve the privileges of those who already hold economic power.
The conclusion, then, is clear. If we are to rebuild a society that works for people rather than for markets, we must reclaim economics from the myth of neutrality. We must see it again as political economy.
That means restoring moral purpose to economic debate.
It means demanding that questions of tax, spending, and ownership be judged by whether they advance collective well-being, not just by whether they please the bond markets.
It means recognising that the economy is not an abstract machine, but the sum of our shared choices about how to live together.
Political economy is not a return to the past. It is the recovery of the reality of living together in community.
It is the insistence that, if economics is to serve humanity, it must once again begin and end with politics.
A copy of this post is now in the glossary to this blog under political economy.
Comments
When commenting, please take note of this blog's comment policy, which is available here. Contravening this policy will result in comments being deleted before or after initial publication at the editor's sole discretion and without explanation being required or offered.
Thanks for reading this post.
You can share this post on social media of your choice by clicking these icons:
There are links to this blog's glossary in the above post that explain technical terms used in it. Follow them for more explanations.
You can subscribe to this blog's daily email here.
And if you would like to support this blog you can, here:
Back in the day, what you call “Political Economy” was just “Economics”. Somewhere along the line (and I am not sure when but a guess would be 1970s) “Economics” became narrowed down to become “Econometrics” – a quantitative subject. Now, Econometrics has its place but not at the exclusion of everything else.
A long time ago when I was coming to the end of my Maths degree an Economics tutor tried to recruit me (and other mathematicians) to his post-grad Econometrics course. “But I know nothing about economics” I said. “Good, then you start without prejudice. It is easy to teach mathematicians Economics but impossible to teach PPE graduates maths…. or, indeed, anything at all!”
Thankfully, I declined the offer and learnt what little economics I know in real life.
🙂
Polanyi crucially exposes the fallacy of economics as science. The economy is embedded in society, it is what we, as human beings do. The utopian fallacy of the free market, ascribing the laws of science to the economy as if it is akin to the laws of gravity, was always a political ploy. It advocates deny the inevitable fallibility and destructive social consequences of unfettered free markets; and they cover up the inevitable necessity of government to intervene and regulate so that society can continue to function.
Sadly the cry still goes out that a free market economy is what we should be promoting, and that if only governments would stop interfering, then it would work. We can’t say an unregulated free market economy doesn’t work, because it has never been allowed to happen. Catch 22 if ever there was one.
Which is why we need to keep plugging away, telling the whole truth, and nothing but.
Our esteemed Chancellor, Rachel Reeves told us, vis a vis her forthcoming Big Autumn Financial Lie, she
“can’t leave welfare untouched”.
https://www.benefitsandwork.co.uk/news/reeves-says-she-%E2%80%9Ccan%E2%80%99t-leave-welfare-untouched%E2%80%9D
(in particular, the Motability scheme)
Now, there’s a statement ripe for anaysis according to the tenets of political economy. Particularly as she will ride from No.11 Downing St. to the Commons in a publicly financed ministerial car, to speak to >600 MPs most of whom will have journeyed there at public expense to hear her lying to them about who has the “broadest shoulders” and should therefore be “bearing the load”.
Thanks for that – exactly my thoughts – but expressed more elegantly.
A noble calling, Richard, to try and explain political economy to the man on the Clapham bus. The great prize, which is certainly within reach, is to see society and governments change the current tune once the general public ‘get it’. You are doing a great job with your very clear explanations and videos, but you are a professor and for some reason many people are not grasping what to me are fairly simple concepts. Maybe you might consider some additional way of speaking directly to a person who hitherto has shown no interest in economics, yet has at least a passing interest in politics. I’m really just thinking out loud here, but say one of your blog followers was a well known face to the public, but not famous for their intellect( I don’t mean thick). Supposing they understood economics at a basic level. How would they tell other people about it. I’m thinking of someone like Danny Dyer who is very critical in a humorous way of the last two government’s lack of care. This hit home on social media in a big way. I know it’s very difficult to do this and it’s really just an add-on to the excellent presentations available on YouTube and the blog. The public are hard to reach directly outside of the main media, and if they cannot be reached they cannot know the truth.
Excellent question
And I have no idea…
But I will think about it
Powerful post Richard with so many quotes to extract and draw ordinary people’s attention to I’ll have to repost it numerous times. Thanks
Thanks